• Loading stock data...
World Featured Finance News trade

Trumpian tariffs are import substitution industrialization 2.0

The new Trumpian tariffs are not the familiar protectionism G7 nations have applied for decades. Instead of shielding particular sectors, they wall off the entire American goods-producing economy from foreign competition. This is precisely the logic of 20th-century import substitution industrialisation – a strategy widely tried, and widely abandoned, because it raised costs, bred inefficiency, and undercut export performance. The rise of global value chains turned such tariff walls from protection into destruction. No one has tried import substitution industrialisation since – apart from America in 2025.

A 21st-century revival of a 20th-century mistake

America is running a bold economic experiment. Call it Economic Trumpism. Its core is disarmingly simple:

  • Wall off America’s goods-producing economy from foreign competition and imported industrial inputs and hope industry flourishes inside.

No elaborate industrial policy. No bothersome planning. None of that old-fashioned stuff. Just a big, beautiful tariff wall to shield America from rapacious foreign competition. Best of all? According to the current US administration, it costs not a penny. Just the opposite: it shovels billions into the Treasury’s coffers.

Why is this an experiment? Don’t all nations apply tariffs?

The answer is simple. Trumpian tariffs are not the familiar tariffs aimed at protecting a favoured sector; the President has put up a tariff wall around the entire economy. And that’s not something that has been tried for decades in a G7 nation.

From sectoral shield to protectionist wall

To see the distinction, recall a classic US example. As part of a trade spat with Europe, the US put a 25% tariff on imported pickup trucks. Since it was in retaliation for Europe’s regulations that banned US chicken meat, the 25% tariff is still called the ‘chicken tax’. Ordinary autos weren’t included, so their tariff was negotiated down to about 2.5%.

The asymmetry reshaped what US producers built (large pickups) and what foreign firms avoided exporting to the US. For example, Toyota largely abandoned direct export of pickups to the US and instead built factories in America to avoid the tariff. That is how narrow tariffs ‘work’: they shift resources for a few sectors.

But broad tariffs, covering most manufactured goods, are a different animal. They raise input costs across the board, they invite retaliation and trade diversion, they fragment supply chains, and they induce tariff-engineering (re-routing, re-labelling, re-designing to slip under the wall). The mechanism isn’t a gentle nudge; it’s a shove applied to every factory in the country, including those that rely on imported intermediates to stay competitive.

Structuralist development economics and import substitution industrialisation

Trump-like, high and broad tariffs were very popular in developing nations (as we called them back when they were doing it) up to the 1990s. Indeed, almost all developing nations believed that putting tariffs on everything from everyone was a winning policy. And when I say high, I mean high! Levels that would make Donald Trump blush (metaphorically). The US average tariff is set to raise to about 20% from its current 9% (it was under 3% in 2024). That is nothing compared to the standard operating procedure in Latin America by in the 1970s and 1980s (see Figure 1).

Figure 1 Most developing countries had high tariff walls before 1995

Figure 1 Most developing countries had high tariff walls before 1995
Figure 1 Most developing countries had high tariff walls before 1995
Note: Based on World Bank data that I used in my 2016 book, The Great Convergence.

These experiments with Trump-like tariffs failed, but there was a beautiful theory behind them – a theory that is now discredited but was, and still is, compelling in its simplicity. The economic theory behind import substitution industrialisation (ISI) was laid down in the mid-20th century by economists like Raúl Prebisch and Hans Singer.

The economic part was quite simple: in a world where demand creates supply, putting up high tariffs shifted domestic demand from imported goods to locally produced goods. The new demand would create new domestic industry. Presto! Industrialisation is driven by the substitution of imports with domestically made goods. That’s where the name ISI comes from.

There was a political, or grievance, aspect of the theory as well that tended to get many people quite heated about the theory being morale as well as economically justifiable.

Donald Trump claims that the US is victimised by the world trade system. That is exactly how the ‘structuralist’ school viewed the world economy back then (and many still do today). It was rigged against developing nations by colonists. In one version, the rich got richer because the poor got poorer. 

To escape this ‘unequalising trade’ trap, the advice of the structuralist development crowd was as simple as Economic Trumpism: stop importing manufactured goods, build them at home behind tariff walls, and industrialisation would follow (see Prebisch 1950 or Wallerstein 1974).

My frequent readers will recognise this as the forerunner of Trump’s ‘grievance doctrine’. Immanuel Wallerstein’s world systems theory cast the global economy as an exploitative ‘core–periphery’ structure. The rich, industrialised core supposedly locked the periphery into underdevelopment through colonialism, imperialism, and unequal exchange. The political conclusion was compelling: if the system is rigged, the only way out is to build walls around the national economy and force industrialisation by decree.

Why import substitution industrialisation failed

There was nothing wrong with the economic or emotional justification of the high, broad tariffs. The problem is that reality didn’t cooperate.

Of course, the demand-creates-supply did work for some industries, so it seemed to be validated in the early years. ISI worked in bringing ‘light industry’ inside the tariff wall (Balassa 1981, 1985). But when it came to the more sophisticated heavy industry (autos, chemicals, machinery, electronics, etc.), the domestic market wasn’t sufficient to create domestic supply. The tariffs didn’t work.

Only a handful of nations managed to industrialise significantly, and most of those were in East Asia. But they did not rely on indiscriminate tariffs. Instead, they combined targeted protection with export discipline, state-directed credit, and careful government–business coordination. Protection was temporary, conditional, and linked to performance (Amsden 1989).

Consumers paid high prices for low-quality goods. Export performance was dismal or entirely absent. By the 1980s, many countries that had embraced ISI were wondering about the wisdom of following a 1950s-era theory in the age of modern manufacturing.

As Figure 1 shows, there was a near-universal volte-face on tariffs in the 1990s. Why was that?

Globalisation changed and turned protectionism into destructionism

At the end of the 20th century, industrial protectionism turned into industrial destructionism. For developing nations, the nature of industrialisation changed. Instead of keeping tariffs high to keep industrial goods out, they had to lower industrial tariffs so G7 manufacturing firms would include them in their global value chains (GVCs).

With the ICT revolution, production stages no longer fit neatly inside national borders; they stretch across countries. Autos are not made in America; they are made in what I called ‘Factory North America’. Autos are not made in Germany; they are made in ‘Factory Europe’. Autos are not made in Japan; they are made in ‘Factory Asia’. The whole world of manufacturing changed around 1990s.

In my 2016 book, The great convergence: information technology and the New Globalization, I called this ‘globalisation’s second unbundling’. (The first unbundling was goods crossing borders; the second unbundling was factories and G7 manufacturing knowhow crossing borders.) The phenomenon subsequently became known as the ‘Global Value Chain (GVC) Revolution’. 

Indeed, it is exactly this change in the nature of globalisation that led the developing nations to abandon broad and high tariff walls.

Economic Trumpism in the 21st century

That brings us back to 2025. Unlike the developing nations of the 1960s and 1970s, the US is already a fully industrialised, high-income economy. It does not need to ‘force’ industrialisation behind tariff walls. Quite the opposite: it relies on global supply chains, advanced services, and integrated capital markets. Walling off the entire goods-producing sector is not just unnecessary, it is counterproductive. The US is in the process of hobbling its own factories, raising prices for its own consumers, and pushing investment and innovation offshore.

Don’t take my word for it. Look at what has happened to manufacturing employment under the second Trump administration (see Figure 2).

Figure 2 US factory jobs: Down on Trump’s trade war

Figure 2 US factory jobs: Down on Trump’s trade war
Figure 2 US factory jobs: Down on Trump’s trade war

The basic problem is that a lack of demand is not the constraining factor in American manufacturing; it’s the workforce. The group of workers who are able and willing to work on a factory floor is shrinking. Almost 400,000 manufacturing jobs are currently unfilled, according to the Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Conclusion: Tools versus walls, sectors versus nations

The bottom line? Tariffs have always been political, but they usually work as tools to protect favoured sectors. They are narrow, targeted, and often effective in shaping industrial outcomes (even if those outcomes are inefficient).

Trump’s tariffs are different. They aim to wall off the entire economy, reviving an old, discredited development strategy that failed almost everywhere it was tried.

So is ‘Economic Trumpism’ import substitution 2.0? Yes. And my guess is the ISI 2.0 will end the same way ISI 1.0 ended – economic failure and eventual abandonment.

Broad tariff walls don’t build nations. If they build anything at all, they build inefficiencies. In the end, Trump’s tariffs may succeed in mobilising short-run political support, but they will fail to protect American prosperity. As I said in a recent Factful Friday, “Trump won politically, but America lost economically”.

Source : VOXeu

GLOBAL BUSINESS AND FINANCE MAGAZINE

GLOBAL BUSINESS AND FINANCE MAGAZINE

About Author

Leave a comment

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

You may also like

World

Openness to trade and regional growth: Evidence from Italy during the First Globalisation

The economic, social, and political consequences of globalisation have been a hot topic in the public debate over the last
Banking Finance

Can African trade integration be a game changer?

New World Bank research shows the agreement among 54 countries would likely draw more foreign direct investment, amplifying its benefits