Policies aimed at reducing economic fluctuations primarily focus on disruptive recessions, but booms may also have hidden costs. A rise in wages increases the opportunity cost of schooling, potentially leading students to abandon school prematurely. This column examines the impact of a tax reform in Iceland that cut taxes to zero for one year and finds that the rise in the opportunity cost of schooling led to higher dropout rates, a permanent loss in educational attainment, and substantial losses in lifetime earnings. These findings suggest that the cost of business cycles may be larger than previously thought and highlight the potential benefits of education policies in mitigating these costs.
Business cycles are costly. Recessions damage the economy, destroy jobs, and lead to persistent losses in earnings. An extensive macroeconomic literature has quantified the welfare costs of recessions, emphasising their impact on the level and volatility of household consumption (e.g. Lucas 1987, 2003, Krebs 2007, Krusell et al. 2009). However, economic booms may also have costs. Temporary wage increases raise the opportunity cost of schooling, potentially reducing school enrollment and increasing dropout rates (Mincer 1958, Becker 1962). Through this channel, booms may permanently reduce human capital.
Research has documented reduced school enrollment and increased dropout rates during periods of hot labour markets (e.g. Cameron and Taber 2004), housing booms (Charles et al. 2018), natural resource booms (Black et al. 2005, Cascio and Narayan 2020), and following factory openings (Atkin 2016).
Ultimately, the macroeconomic consequences depend on how economic booms affect human capital and productivity in the long run. In a recent paper (Sigurdsson 2024), I provide novel insights into this phenomenon, exploiting a tax reform in Iceland to study this effect. In the late 1980s, Iceland transitioned to a pay-as-you-earn tax system from one where current-year taxes were based on the previous year’s income (Bianchi et al. 2001, Sigurdsson 2023). During the transition year of 1987, no taxes were collected on income earned that year. This created an ideal natural experiment: a one-year wage increase with no effects on lifetime returns to education.
Educational scarring of men
To estimate the effect of the tax-free year on school dropout rates and educational attainment, I compare teenagers around the compulsory schooling age. Specifically, I compare those who had turned 16 and completed compulsory schooling, making them eligible to leave school during the tax-free year, to younger students who were still required to stay in school.
Figure 1 presents the estimated effect on educational attainment, measured by both degree completion and completed years of schooling, for men and women separately. The data reveal a significant difference in men’s degree completion emerging at the expected graduation age of 20, consistent with men dropping out of school during the tax-free year. I estimate a 5 percentage point, or 8%, decrease in the completion of post-compulsory education. This effect is driven by increased dropout rates from four-year academic tracks, typically attended between the ages of 16 and 20, which are the qualifications for university enrollment.
In principle, when faced with a temporary increase in the opportunity cost of schooling, students might choose to temporarily substitute schooling with work, planning to return and complete their education after the tax-free year. However, Figure 1 demonstrates that this was not the case. Young men who left school during the tax-free year did not return later to complete their education, resulting in a permanent education loss.
Figure 1 Effect of tax-free year on school dropout and educational attainment
Source: Sigurdsson (2024)
Interestingly, unlike men, women did not show a similar dropout pattern, despite being equally affected by the zero-tax policy and constituting a larger share of junior college students at the time.
Loss in lifetime earnings
Dropping out of school led to significant losses in lifetime earnings. Figure 2 shows that while dropouts initially earned higher incomes, their earnings gradually lagged behind those of their peers in adulthood. At prime working age, the tax-free year reduced earnings for affected men by approximately $2,100, or 5.1%. When translated into a causal effect of dropout on earnings, using the estimated effect on dropout discussed above, the estimate suggests that if those who dropped out had completed their education, they would have doubled their annual prime-age earnings.
Figure 2 Effects of Tax-free year on labour earnings in the short and long run
Source: Sigurdsson (2024)
The cost of business cycles
The evidence suggests that business cycles may be costlier than previously thought. Traditional estimates focus on variations in income and consumption during recessions, with potential long-run effects (Shen and Malmendier 2021). However, these estimates overlook the effects that booms may have on educational attainment.
The results presented my paper allow for the quantification of this channel using an estimate of the elasticity of years of schooling to a transitory change in the opportunity cost of school attendance. The elasticity estimate suggests that a transitory boom raising teenage wages by 10% leads to a 1.5% permanent loss in years of schooling for the affected cohorts.
This reduction in schooling is likely to have significant negative consequences for long-term productivity and output. Back-of-the-envelope calculations for Iceland suggest that the human capital loss in the 1987 tax-free year resulted in a 0.1-0.2% reduction in aggregate output in 2020.
While recessions may counteract the loss in human capital by lowering opportunity costs and leading students to stay longer in school, they may also negatively affect educational attainment through binding borrowing constraints and reduced resources. While both forces may be at play, existing research has found recent recessions to reduce rather than increase educational attainment (e.g. Hilger 2016, Stuart 2022).
Implications for policy
What does this imply for policy? The evidence suggests that education policies can complement macroeconomic policies in mitigating the cost of business cycles. One promising policy candidate is raising the compulsory schooling age. Existing evidence indicates that this approach can effectively increase educational attainment and retain students in school beyond the compulsory age (Oreopoulos 2007).
I estimate that if Iceland’s compulsory schooling age had been 17 instead of 16 during the tax-free year, the loss in educational attainment could have been reduced by approximately 40%.
Alternatively, policymakers could consider procyclical education policies aimed at keeping students in school when opportunity costs are high. For example, increasing education subsidies or lowering interest rates on student loans could counteract the higher opportunity costs and the incentives to leave school.
Source : VOXeu