• Loading stock data...
Banking Featured Finance

Deciphering the disinflation process

US inflation surged in the early post-COVID period, driven by various economic shocks including supply chain disruptions and labour supply constraints. Following its peak at 6.6% in September 2022, US core consumer price index inflation has come down rapidly over the last two years, falling to 3.6% recently. This column shows that the interaction between supply chain pressures and labour market tightness amplified the inflation surge in 2021, and argues that these same forces have worked in reverse since late 2022, accelerating the disinflationary process. The current episode contrasts with periods where the economy was hit by shocks to either imported inputs or to labour alone. 

How did supply-side pressures contribute to the surge in inflation of the early post-COVID period (e.g. Di Giovanni et al. 2023) and to the subsequent inflation decline? In a recent paper (Amiti et al. 2024), we analyse the inflation surge. We examine three supply-side shocks: first, supply chain bottlenecks which increased the prices of imported intermediate inputs (input price shock); second, rising labour market tightness due to declining labour supply, for example resulting from early retirements (labour supply shock); and third, supply chain pressures experienced by foreign competitors, which allowed US firms to expand their markups without losing market share (foreign competitor shock). Through the lens of our model, the combination of the three shocks generated a peak inflation surge of around 3 percentage points above the assumed steady state inflation level of 2%, about three quarters of the rise in core CPI inflation observed during 2021 and 2022. Importantly, the combined shock has an amplified effect in our model: when the shocks hit the economy jointly, inflation increases by 0.7 percentage points more than when they hit separately. 

We use the model to analyse the decline of inflation from its peak as the combined shock dissipates. Specifically, we compare the scenario where the inflation peak is generated by the combined shock versus a hypothetical scenario where the input price, labour market, and foreign competitor shocks occur separately and the inflation responses are added up. In Figure 1, the red dashed line represents the pace of disinflation in the scenario when the shocks hit the economy separately. After 10 quarters, inflation has fallen by about 1.8 percentage points. The solid black line shows the inflation path following a joint shock. We find that inflation falls more rapidly in this case, declining by about 2.2 percentage points after 10 quarters, more than two thirds of the inflation surge of 3.0%. 

Figure 1 Moderation of inflation following joint shock versus separate shocks 

Figure 1 Moderation of inflation following joint shock versus separate shocks 
Figure 1 Moderation of inflation following joint shock versus separate shocks 
Notes: Figure shows impulse response of core consumer price index (CPI) inflation, that is, all items excluding food and energy. The red dashed line traces out the sum of the impulse response to a separate import price shock, a labour disutility shock, and a competition shock. The black solid line shows the joint effect of all three shocks simultaneously.

Substitution between labour and imported inputs generates faster disinflation

Why does a joint shock generate an amplified inflation response in our model?  Intuitively, when a joint shock to imported input prices and labour hits the economy, substituting between labour and imported intermediates becomes less effective for firms. In normal times, firms can shift away from any factor experiencing an isolated cost increase (e.g. Feenstra et al. 2018). For example, firms could absorb wage pressures in the domestic economy by replacing domestically sourced inputs, which use domestic labour, with imported intermediates from abroad, effectively using foreign labour. When intermediate input costs and labour costs both rise at the same time, as in the immediate post-COVID period, the scope for this substitution is diminished. As a result, firms cannot control costs as effectively, amplifying the cost pass-through into inflation. Moreover, the supply chain problems that foreign competitors experienced in the immediate post-COVID period reduced the effective competition faced by domestic producers, further increasing domestic firms’ pass-through of adverse shocks into prices. We provide empirical support for this amplification mechanism in our paper.

Turning to the disinflation, according to our model the same forces that generated the inflation surge have worked in reverse. Easier access to foreign inputs, coupled with a less tight domestic labour market, have made it easier for domestic producers to substitute again between labour and intermediates. For example, reduced supply chain bottlenecks might make it more appealing to source additional inputs from abroad to contain wage pressures. Our model suggests that this ability to substitute between inputs has contributed to a more rapid decline in inflation than if either input price pressures or labour market pressures had eased in isolation. Increased competition with foreign firms has further dampened US producers’ markups, putting additional downward pressure on prices. 

Supply chain disruptions have helped low-skilled workers

An implication of our model is that the supply-side shocks of the early post-COVID period may have helped low-skilled US workers. When the substitution between domestic labour and intermediate inputs is impaired, low-skilled US workers benefit the most due to the additional labour demand to produce inputs in the US. Consistent with this implication, workers in the bottom quartile of the wage distribution experienced strong wage growth in 2020 to early 2022, leading to the wage compression seen in Figure 2. The recent normalisation of supply chain conditions has the reverse effect, as substitution between US labour and foreign inputs becomes again more effective. Consequently, low-skilled workers are particularly harmed. The recent decline in wage growth particularly at the bottom of the wage distribution is consistent with this implication.

Figure 2 Low-wage workers’ wage growth has moderated

Figure 2 Low-wage workers’ wage growth has moderated
Figure 2 Low-wage workers’ wage growth has moderated
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta.
Notes: Figure shows the twelve-month moving average of median twelve-month growth in hourly earnings by wage quartile. The first quartile represents the lowest earnings level.

Conclusion

In this column, we have argued that the combined shock to imported inputs and labour supply may have amplified the inflation surge in the early post-COVID period. As the shock has dissipated, our model suggests that the same mechanism has worked in reverse and accelerated the decline in inflation. The amplification effect may be one explanation for the faster than expected disinflation over the last two years.

We do not expect the supply-side shocks to fully explain the rise and fall of inflation due to the important role played by demand-side factors, such as government transfers during the pandemic.  Importantly, these demand-side factors could partially be responsible for the supply-side factors we observe. 

Going forward, in light of our model’s results, we expect the downward pressure on inflation due to the amplification forces highlighted here to diminish since supply chain conditions have returned to normal, limiting the disinflation from the interaction with the labour market. 

Source : VOXeu

GLOBAL BUSINESS AND FINANCE MAGAZINE

GLOBAL BUSINESS AND FINANCE MAGAZINE

About Author

Leave a comment

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

You may also like

Banking

Banks’ exposures to high-carbon assets may represent a medium-term vulnerability for the financial system

Climate change is rapidly being recognised as a potential source of financial risk by regulators and supervisors (Claessens et al.
Banking Finance

Can African trade integration be a game changer?

New World Bank research shows the agreement among 54 countries would likely draw more foreign direct investment, amplifying its benefits